Does Meritocracy really work or not?
Reading the mystery Googler’s anti-diversity manifesto really pissed me off. The least of the problems was his terrible use of footnotes.
It’s easy to have a knee-jerk reaction, so I’m not going to go into all the bad arguments because frankly there are too many. If someone can’t identify the issues with citing biological differences as a basis for discrimination, it’s not likely that logic or research is going to sway their mind.
I would like to have a serious discussion about diversity, but I’m not going to treat racist and sexist claims as if they qualify for serious discussion.
So if we’re going to seriously discuss the actual intellectual arguments that genuinely smart people seem to actually believe in, I’ll try and dust off my philosophy brain. I strongly encourage anyone to find the holes in this argument and then build it up to make it better as I’m going to skip over or simplify some things.
This may invite a lot of trolls, but so be it. The one upside to the recent sexual harassment scandals in venture capital and the mystery Googler’s anti-diversity manifesto is that now we can see the issue in broad daylight.
I would rather see the issue and speak out against it than be in the dark or be silent.
I will focus on one claim that seems to be the general undercurrent of all anti-diversity arguments in the valley: Meritocracy is the best form of governance.
Faith in Meritocracy
There is an absolute insistence and faith in meritocracy from many, many people in Silicon Valley.[1] In case you’re not familiar, a meritocracy is a political system where power is allocated to those with the most ability. In the case of Silicon Valley, this equates to “the best ideas win and the best people get promoted.”
The idea that Silicon Valley is a functioning meritocracy is then used as a basis for saying that policies like affirmative action and diversity quotas are bad. I am not agreeing with this argument, just making sure the argument against diversity policies is clear.
The basic argument is:
- This is a meritocracy.
- Meritocracy is good.
- In a meritocracy, only ability is considered for advancement.
- Diversity policies require factors outside of ability to be considered for advancement.
- Therefore diversity policies undermine meritocracy.
- Therefore diversity policies are bad.
Diversity at Euclid Co.
To make this simpler and more concrete, let’s say we have a company called Euclid Co. with a population of 60 blue squares and 40 red triangles. We have 10 job openings for senior polygon, and only 10 percent of the population is qualified for this position. This means 6 blue squares qualify and 4 red triangles qualify. Let’s assume that the population outside of Euclid Co. is 50 percent blue squares and 50 percent red triangles.
The meritocracy argument says that any diversity quota that dictates that the jobs be given to a 50-50 split to match the population would be unfair. This is because only 4 red triangles qualify, so the sixth blue square is going to be shut out of its dream job because a red triangle is going to be randomly allocated to the senior polygon position that they don’t deserve.
The blue square is sad.
How Meritocracies Really Work
This argument equates any diversity policy designed to combat discrimination with discrimination against the majority. It flips the anti-discrimination argument like this:
- Discrimination is bad.
- Diversity policies are discriminatory.
- Therefore diversity policies are bad.
Essentially it challenges anyone campaigning against discrimination to justify why their diversity policy isn’t discriminatory and regards any such policy as an undeserved handout.
To put it even simpler, the meritocracy argument says that diversity policies tilt the level playing field in favor of the undeserving.
Bias in Big Company Hierarchies
Let’s reset the scenario at Euclid Co. and see what happens when we introduce bias. We’ll make the company bigger so the math is easier. There are 60,000 blue squares and 40,000 red triangles. There are 10,000 senior polygon positions open, and 10 percent of the population is qualified: 6,000 blue squares and 4,000 red triangles.
Unfortunately, there is a small bias in the promotion process. In a 100 question skill assessment, one of the questions is, “Why are 90 degree angles the most perfect type of angle?”
Red triangles, of course, don’t understand the question because they enjoy all sorts of angles. They are triangles, after all, and come in all sorts of angles, whereas squares only have 90 degree angles. So the triangles get the question wrong, and the squares get it right.
However, believing that a 90 degree angle is perfect doesn’t have much impact on the job performance of a senior polygon and there are lots of other questions that don’t predict job performance. So let’s imagine that this question or another similar factor has introduced a minor 1 percent bias.
This small 1 percent bias means that 11 percent of blue squares are considered for promotion and only 9 percent of red triangles are considered. That’s 6,600 “qualified” blue squares and 3,600 “qualified” red triangles —10,200 candidates total.
So if there are only 10,000 positions open and they are divided evenly among the pool of candidates, we will get 6,471 senior blue squares and 3,529 senior red triangles.
This small 1 percent bias has already resulted in a loss of representation. From 40 percent to 35.29 percent.
Continuing this math with the same small 1 percent bias, we will have only 30.86 percent red triangles represented at the VP level, 26.75 percent represented at the senior VP level, and down to 23 percent at the C level.
More levels of seniority will compound biased representation. In other words, hierarchies amplify any bias in the system.
(For those wondering, even a “small” company of only 2000 people can have 9 levels of seniority. Also, yes…the lack of diversity in the U.S. Congress probably has something to do with this phenomenon.)
The Bias of a Growing Company
Some will argue, “We don’t have hierarchies. We don’t even have titles!”
First, get real. Even when we remove titles, people sort themselves into a pecking order. People use other ways of indicating social status, including who talks first and last in meetings. But okay, let’s just assume that Euclid Co. has no hierarchies.
Will this lack of hierarchy eliminate the problem? Maybe, but only if that company doesn’t hire anyone.
Let’s say that Euclid Co. starts with a small population of 5 red triangles and 5 blue squares, and there are no promotions. Euclid Co. is going to grow from 10 people to about 10,000 — every Silicon Valley company’s dream.
As Euclid Co. starts to grow, there is a slight 1 percent bias in the hiring process that gives new blue square hires an 11 percent chance of getting the job and red triangles a 9 percent chance of getting the job.
In the beginning, this makes very little difference. By the time Euclid Co. is ~20 people it will be ~51.58 percent blue and ~48.42 percent red. But things quickly escalate.
By the time the company is ~10,000 people, it will be 69.69 percent blue and 30.31 percent red. Again a pretty radical problem in representation introduced by a relatively small bias over time just by a bad hiring process.
It’s true that we don’t hire fractional people so the math here is off. However, rounding the hiring bias makes the situation worse. With standard rounding, the company will be 76.19 percent blue at just 21 people and 99.95 percent blue at ~10,000 people.
Time will amplify any bias inherent in the system. Share on XMeritocracy by Democracy
Of course, some will say, “Our hiring process has no biases.” The variant of this that I have heard is, “Our hiring process has no biases because it’s peer-to-peer and we vote.”
This is a kind of magical “democracy beats racism” in a meritocracy argument. Unfortunately, in a democracy, discrimination can go viral.
Let’s say blue squares are really biased and only hire other blue squares. Red triangles hire only red triangles. Clearly no problem. Everyone is equally biased and the representation will remain proportional.
However, if only one part of the population is biased, problems show up quickly. Let’s say that blue squares only hire blue squares while red squares hire equally.
If the population starts at 50 red and 50 blue, in just one round of hiring, blue will hire another 50 blues. Red will meanwhile hire 25 reds and 25 blues. So in just one round, there will be 62.50 percent blue and 37.5 percent red.
Democracy Can Actually Help
It’s worth digging out a spreadsheet and playing with the numbers in many of these scenarios because a relatively fair-minded population can erase a lot of biases over a sufficient length of time by voting. If you’re more technically minded, try playing with genetic algorithms to see the same thing.
It gets very interesting when constraints are put on the population, such as a limited number of senior polygon positions, limited venture capital funding, limited housing, and so forth. But that’s too complicated for a Sunday night essay.
The end result is that if blue is only slightly biased, this effect may be relatively insignificant and the bias in representation can approach a limit. However, that’s the point. If people make great decisions, democracy is great.
This greatness requires two things:
- All people are perfectly rational.
- All people have access to perfect information.
Neither of these are true.
Even if the counterargument is, “In our company we make perfectly rational decisions,” it doesn’t matter. There just has to be some bias somewhere in the system for things to quickly get out of whack.
Evidence for Being Perfectly Rational
Perfect information is interesting, so let’s go back to Euclid Co. and ask ourselves, “How do we know which red triangles and blue squares are qualified to be senior polygons?”
The unfortunate answer is, “We can tell they are qualified because they were promoted.”
In other words, the fact that they were promoted is sometimes considered proof that they were promoted for the right reason.
This is an argument we’ve heard in venture capital. Successful venture capitalists claim that they have “pattern matching” powers. The evidence for this is that they have been successful.
This is an overly simplistic representation of that argument, but it’s sadly common. (You can read just some of why there aren’t enough women in VC or why minorities can’t get VC funding.)
I am not saying that there are no VCs or angels with good judgment.
I am saying that this is a terrible argument. It has the same intellectual rigor of a casino lounge lizard explaining their magical rabbit’s foot. “I haven’t lost yet!”
Everyone is lucky until they lose. Share on XA good argument to prove that the “pattern matching” system actually works would be to predict which companies would be successful and track the results without tipping the scales by actually investing in them.
Alternatively, the minimal amount of rigor would be to create a control group and actually track companies that did not match the pattern. In other words, predict failure and be falsifiable.
Sadly, few research scientists have the budget to compete against VCs!
Again, before every VC gets furious with me (too late), I’m not saying there aren’t good and bad VCs, just that the argument of “I can prove my system is successful by looking at my selective sample set of data that I am helping out with money and connections with no control group to hold me accountable” is a terrible argument to prove an investor has a good or bad system.
It’s also a terrible argument to prove that a compensation system is unbiased.
Information Flow in a System
The best way to prove that a system is flawed is, of course, to simply wait. A VC who has just been lucky will eventually start losing. Those red triangles or blue squares that are unfairly promoted will get fired if they can’t perform.
So the counterargument is, “unfair promotions will eventually be weeded out.”
This would be true in a closed system with perfect information. If a senior blue square is promoted for unfair reasons and then underperforms, they will leave the company.
Sadly, that’s not how it works, and I think that everyone knows at least one idiot of every race, gender, and ethnic background who consistently manages to avoid being fired despite gross incompetence. However, let’s just assume Euclid Co. is amazing and they figure it out eventually. Then from the perspective of Euclid Co., meritocracy is eventually reinstated.
However, when that underperforming blue square from Euclid Co. goes to get a new job at Riemann Inc., it applies for a senior polygon position based on its resume at Euclid Co. showing a senior polygon position. Euclid Co. has a great reputation for only promoting the best people, so this counts as a strong point in Mr. Square’s favor in the application process.
This would be impossible if there was 100 percent information flow from Euclid Co. to Riemann Inc. Riemann Inc. would reject the blue square on the basis of a bad reference.
So, out of all our personal experiences both hiring and being hired, does anyone really believe that the interviewer did a perfect reference check? Have you, me, or anyone else you know ever pushed the interviewer to contact the most favorable reference? Will the great brand value of Euclid Co. introduce a subtle 1 percent bias at a different company?
As it turns out, switching companies is a faster career path for most people and generally results in higher salary.
To get this system to work, Euclid Co. needs to be a perfect meritocracy, automatically correct for any bias, and broadcast this information to the rest of the world.
Even a perfect meritocracy may unintentionally introduce subtle biases in other parts of the system.
Assumptions for Meritocracy
We’ve already seen how even a small 1 percent bias will have a large effect on the representation of Euclid Co. In order for meritocracy to fix this, there are some fundamental requirements:
- The evaluation process is perfect.
- There is perfect information flow.
- It’s a closed system.
Number 3 is obviously wrong in Silicon Valley (and everywhere). Those people that are inclined to follow this path are likely busy looking for John Galt and not reading this.
Number 2 is also something I have never heard anyone seriously claim (even the Googler).
Number 1 is the unassailable self-doubt that the meritocratic argument must fall back on. “Our evaluation process is perfect.”
Or more specifically, “I am infallible.”
I honestly have no counterargument here, and that is where the heart of my frustration lies.
We All Make Mistakes
I have made some pretty brutal mistakes in my life. I have said sexist things and been blissfully unaware of them. (Thank you to those that have appropriately called me on it.)
I’m sure I’ve made even more mistakes that I’m not aware of.
I’m also a consultant, which means I get paid to sound very confident, even when figuring things out on the fly.
But even in my most arrogant moments, such as when I’ve just said something very clever and been pat on the back, I cannot imagine that I don’t make mistakes or hold biases.
There is no way for me to reconcile that argument or even have a discussion with those that believe that they do not have any biases and that there is a “level playing field.”
I look at the distorted representation and it tells me there is not a level playing field. That same data tells others that there are “biological differences” because it’s a meritocracy.
Perhaps I’m stupid for even writing this argument out longhand. But I somehow hope that we might all take a moment and consider, “Hey, maybe this isn’t a meritocracy. Maybe there is a slight chance that I have a 1 percent bias.”
If so, maybe we should introduce something to correct that bias.
Conclusion
The argument that meritocracy is the best form of governance isn’t wrong so much as it is naïve. A true meritocracy would be wonderful. A “level playing field” would be amazing.
But we do not live in a level playing field. People are biased. People are always biased. People will likely continue being biased. Even chatbots sometimes turn out to be racist.
It is frankly astonishing that it’s even necessary to convince people that after several hundred (or several thousand) years of institutionalized racism, sexism, and general insanity that there might still be an element of bias in the world.
Shockingly, we can’t just ignore history and start the slate clean as of now. Electing Obama didn’t fix that. This is not a post-racial world.
The common argument for meritocracy is really backwards. When people claim that a minority group isn’t getting their share of the pie because they don’t have what it takes, it’s nonsense. What they are really saying is this:
- This is a meritocracy.
- In a meritocracy, only ability should be considered for advancement.
- “Those people” aren’t doing well.
- Therefore “those people” don’t have much ability.
They are using the lack of performance of some group or individual to justify a discriminatory bias because they have utter faith in their own judgment and think they live in a meritocracy.
So this article is for those that say, “Level playing field vs. affirmative action is harder to argue.”
I understand the point, but I disagree. It’s easy to argue that there is no level playing field. It only took me a couple hours on a Sunday night and I’m neither the smartest person in the room nor am I the most informed on this subject.
The default assumption when asked, “Are we biased?” should not be, “I don’t know.” We know enough. The default assumption is, “Yes. We are probably biased.”
There are a lot of great arguments for diversity initiatives and how they help companies innovate. (I was 90 percent done with a post on that when I got distracted by the manifesto.) But here is the argument I wish we would consider together:
- We have many biases, cognitive and otherwise.
- Therefore we are not perfect decision-makers.
- Therefore we are not in a perfect meritocracy.
- Therefore diversity initiatives, however imperfect, might just tilt the playing field back to being level.
Because however unfair diversity initiatives feel to that one sad blue square who has perhaps been unfairly passed over for a promotion, we are far better off as a community when we truly level the playing field.
UPDATE: amirmc on the YC News thread of this post points out this wonderful site The Parable of the Polygons which is a great interactive illustration of some similar points. I wish I had known about it so I could more properly steal from it.
[1] Footnotes are sometimes used like this to imply that there is a reputable source backing up an anecdotal claim. Most people don’t bother to read them. Don’t use footnotes like this. It’s intellectually lazy.